expr:class='"loading" + data:blog.mobileClass'>

Sunday 2 February 2014

Introduction to Global Strategy The Importance of Institutions in International Business


Introduction to Global Strategy

    This note introduces the subject of global strategy by focusing on issues that companies deal with
as they globalize. A company’s strategy is based on its activity choices; selecting any combination of
functional activities involves trade-offs. Global strategy considers that any functional activity can be
performed in a company’s home country or a foreign country. Whereas corporate strategy involves
diversifying a company across industry boundaries, global strategy involves diversifying some or all
of a company’s activities across national borders. Both corporate and global strategy are about
discerning market failures and devising activities that substitute for missing or incomplete markets,
or both. It is possible to have both kinds of diversification, corporate and global, simultaneously.
This note examines when it is profitable for a company to position part or all of its activities across
national borders and how a cross-border business is successfully designed and managed.

The Importance of Institutions in International Business

   Even in a world with near-seamless telecommunications, generally affordable air travel, and the
Internet, countries continue to differ significantly in cultural beliefs, languages, religions, legal
institutions, rules of trade, and political systems. These so-called institutional differences across
countries profoundly influence the nature of globalization and enable certain opportunities for
successful global business strategy while precluding others.
   Institutional differences greatly affect trade and strategic investment between countries. A
country’s wealth and physical location do affect trade; trade falls, on average, 1% for every 1%
increase in the physical distance between any pair of trading countries. Trade also rises with the size
of economies, but somewhat less than proportionately. But institutional differences affect trade far
more than geographic or economic factors. Economists have shown that, controlling for economic
size and physical distance, shared language increases trade between countries by 200%. Studies
indicate that preferential trading arrangements, common currency, and political union increase trade
by 300%. Having a historical colony-colonizer link might increase trade between countries by as
                1much as 900%. A recent study by Siegel, Licht, and Schwartz (2006) also shows that cultural beliefs
about the need to curb abuses of market power are an important determinant of cross-border flows of
equity, debt, and mergers and acquisitions. Companies are more likely to invest where their
countries’ beliefs are shared; thus, companies in countries that impose stricter constraints on abuses
of market power are (controlling for other explanations) more likely to invest in foreign countries that
do likewise. Conversely, companies in countries that more often tolerate abuses of market power are,
again controlling for other potential explanations, more likely to invest in foreign countries with a
________________________________________________________________________________________________________________
Professor Jordan Siegel wrote the original version of this note, “Introduction to Global Strategy,” HBS No. 705-465, which is being replaced by
this version by Professor Jordan Siegel. This note was prepared for the sole purpose of aiding classroom instructors in the Strategy course.
Copyright © 2006 President and Fellows of Harvard College. To order copies or request permission to reproduce materials, call 1-800-545-7685,
write Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA 02163, or go to http://www.hbsp.harvard.edu. No part of this publication may be
reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, used in a spreadsheet, or transmitted in any form or by any means—electronic, mechanical,
photocopying, recording, or otherwise—without the permission of Harvard Business School.

Module Note—Introduction to Global Strategy
similar bent.2 This likely reflects managers’ intuition that fundamental strategic and organizational
 3choices need to be adapted to both formal and informal rules of conduct in the home environment.
   Markets function because they have underlying institutions that enable and constrain certain
transactions. Strong legal institutions that are transparent and protect property rights are
demonstrably good for development; they often give outside investors the confidence to share their
resources with companies in need of finance. Weak legal institutions deter investment by outside
investors and tend to lower market valuations for companies’ assets. Yet even countries eager to
protect property rights find it difficult to combine new legal institutions patterned on foreign models
with existing institutional norms and practices.
    Companies in emerging economies have sought to circumvent the weak local institutions that
impede their development by accepting voluntary compliance with U.S. securities laws in exchange
for having their shares listed on a major U.S. stock exchange. A problem with this remedy, however,
is that U.S. regulators must often rely on foreign regulators to gather the evidence necessary to
enforce U.S. laws. A study by Siegel (2005) has shown that global law enforcement across borders is
so ineffective and vulnerable to corruption in many foreign countries that U.S. securities laws are
often enforced weakly even amid open violations. Because effective law enforcement requires
foreign regulators to cooperate fully in evidence-gathering and asset seizures, outside investors must
rely on foreign companies’ concern for reputation.4 The difficulty of raising the quality of legal
institutions around the world or enacting global enforcement of U.S. securities laws suggests that
institutional differences across countries will continue to be a strong determinant of investment level
within and across borders.
   These differences underscore the reality of a world with many competing models of how to
produce the same product or service, rather than a convergence of one best set of economic and
institutional practices. 5 Because both knowledge and tastes are location-specific, companies
operating in the same industry around the world are often distinct in terms of strategic activities,
organizational practices, and product development. Historical differences in cultures, laws,
availability of technology, and organizational customs engender separate equilibrium models of
production that can be different even when tastes transcend borders.
   This is not to suggest that every country is an island; similarities among countries are
considerable, and significant progress has been made toward market integration. Similarities
support companies’ strategic adaptation to conditions in diverse locations. Also, similarities support
companies’ attempts to realize significant economies of scale by carrying out certain activities in a
central location. Lastly, many differences among countries can be transformed from obstacles into
business opportunities. As discussed later in this note, arbitraging country differences can often
provide substantial profit-generating opportunities.6
    Three types of opportunities constitute Pankaj Ghemawat’s three As of global strategy:
adaptation, aggregation, and arbitrage.7 Adaptation is about modifying an existing business model
to foster success in a foreign environment. Aggregation is about performing a strategic activity in a
centralized location, building economies of scale, and selling the output of the activity to diverse
foreign markets. Arbitrage is about recognizing that market failures occur when different national or
regional markets are connected. These market failures often coexist with long-term differences in
costs or valuations of company output. Such market failures can be exploited by locating company
activities where costs are lowest and selling the output of those activities where valuation is highest.
Just as there would be no need for companies if markets worked efficiently for all types of
transactions, global companies would not exist if there weren’t ongoing institutional barriers to the
exchange of capital, labor, knowledge, and technology.




Module Note—Introduction to Global Strategy
706-448
Adaptation Strategy
   Adaptation is invoked by a multinational company that seeks, for example, to expand a business
unit horizontally across countries. An example is MTV, which has created sister stations across much
of Europe and Asia. Before setting up shop in a foreign country, management needs to comprehend
the elements of the home-market activity set that have been essential to the company’s success. The
company must understand its source of competitive advantage in order to determine whether foreign
host countries will support the transplantation of those strategic elements. Some countries make it
prohibitive to enter their markets, if not through outright protectionism, then at least through
product and labor regulations, antitrust enforcement, zoning laws, and other policies.
   In the current era of globalization, it is usually possible to transplant the central elements of a
company’s strategy. But the culture and institutions of foreign host countries might dictate that other
important elements of a company’s strategy be tailored to the local market. When, for example,
global restaurant chains such as Pizza Hut and Kentucky Fried Chicken establish affiliates in South
Korea, they can continue to offer their core product mix of hamburgers, fried chicken, and pizza, but
must also provide items with kimchi, chili pepper, soybean paste, and other local ingredients.
Importantly, adaptation is often not just about making do under local constraints, but about
leveraging unique local opportunities for higher returns. For example, multinational companies
might have an advantage in recombining local products and services with home-country output, to
produce ever more novel and value-creating products. Multinationals might also establish internal
norms and processes for adapting useful innovations originated in one host-country subsidiary to all
sufficiently similar markets. Lastly, in foreign host markets that lack essential institutions for market
development, multinationals might be able to substitute, for example, as guarantors for transactions
that would otherwise not have taken place. The process of adaptation for a multinational thus
involves not only importing its business model but also serving in such capacities as venture
capitalist, banker, or educator to facilitate various types of local transactions.
    It is sometimes more appropriate to expressly choose not to change any significant feature of an
activity set, but rather to target a defined set of receptive consumers. Mexican broadcasters, for
example, quickly discovered that they could earn sizeable profits from simply exporting the same
telenovelas produced for Mexican viewers to a targeted Hispanic demographic in the United States
and other countries. At other times it makes more sense for a multinational to endeavor to transform
the local environment; witness Star TV’s attempts to shape the regulatory environment for satellite
telecommunications around the globe.
Aggregation Strategy
   Another set of opportunities revolves around aggregation: finding similarities in national markets
and producing a standardized product for these markets. Serving multiple markets with
standardized products can yield economies of scale. Of course, many companies see scale economies
where none exist and perceive nonexistent similarities between markets. When scale economies are
real, however, and in markets that value standardized products produced more economically and
sold more cheaply, aggregation strategies can be profitable. Hyundai Heavy Industries, for example,
a shipbuilder that historically benefited from scale economies by producing a standardized design for
one global shipping market, designs common products for global application and then markets them
aggressively around the world.
3


706-448
Module Note—Introduction to Global Strategy
Arbitrage Strategy
    Arbitrage is one of the opportunities available to companies that want to take advantage of
location-specific differences. Companies that arbitrage labor-cost differences by locating more labor-
intensive activities in countries with low labor costs, for example, will realize an absolute economic
advantage. But because activities that involve sourcing (e.g., from China) can be imitated, any
advantage can be quickly lost. Nor do first movers always have it easy, often encountering
formidable hurdles as they attempt to navigate new institutional environments. Yet significant risk is
also incurred by followers, inasmuch as the earliest entrants might seize absolute economic
advantages and invest profits in their broader set of activities.
   Arbitrage is not limited to labor differences; R&D, production, human resources, IT, and
marketing activities can also be arbitraged across national borders. Some multinationals, for
example, finance much of their activity with cheap sources of capital located in foreign markets.8 On
occasion, unique production technologies, product designs, and marketing practices can be
transplanted to other national contexts in which their value is even greater than in the home market.
AAA Strategies Involve Trade-offs, but Are Not Mutually Exclusive
    Most companies must choose whether to be low-cost or differentiated; typically they cannot be
both. A company cannot offer all types of products to all types of consumers. In making decisions
about its global strategy, a company must often consider adaptation, aggregation, and arbitrage
opportunities simultaneously. Certainly, many strategic choices among these three A strategies will
entail trade-offs, particularly in the areas of organization design and organizational strategy. (See
Reconfiguring the Global Organization later in this note.) For example, aggregation requires centralized
production and decision-making, whereas adaptation often requires a more decentralized
organizational design. Companies with little experience with global strategy will often find it most
effective to concentrate on building a coherent strategy around one of the As before attempting to do
so for two or three concurrently. The stress of trying to formulate strategies around multiple As
simultaneously can overwhelm any organization that lacks a strong competitive advantage and
advanced knowledge of how its strategic choices relate to one another.
   Yet the trade-offs involved in pursuing the AAA strategies concurrently are seldom as complex as
the trade-offs faced by companies that attempt to pursue low cost and differentiation simultaneously.
Moreover, companies often see no choice but to formulate strategies for more than one of the As.
Even as a company tries to standardize a good or service for global sales, it might want to explore
opportunities to arbitrage production. Instead of producing a standardized product at one location
for global application, a company might achieve partial scale economies by adapting its home-
country business model slightly for local use in a foreign subsidiary. The local modification gives the
basic business model broader application, enabling people and ideas to be shared across borders.
Other intermediate strategies include platform or front-to-back approaches, whereby core features of
an activity set are enacted globally while others are modified for local purposes, and clustering,
whereby standardization is focused not on complete global application but on a cluster of similar
countries based on regional colocation or shared culture.9
4


Module Note—Introduction to Global Strategy
706-448
Global Activities: In-House versus Market
   Once a company decides that it can benefit from a global strategy, it must next determine whether
overseas production, sales, and sourcing of talent and capital can be negotiated through the market.
The market is the preferred avenue for global expansion when all of these activities can be efficiently
handled. Multinational companies exist because markets fail; when markets function poorly or are
nonexistent, it makes sense to perform activities within the company.
   As highlighted by Hennart (1982), markets support economic exchange and value creation
principally for the following reasons.10
1.
2.
Market prices provide strong incentives for value-creating actions. In a well-functioning
market, actions that create more value are rewarded with higher prices.
If a project is going to involve multiple investments over time, or is going to generate returns
that will be received at different times far into the future, an entrepreneur needs a well-
functioning market to lock in prices for goods delivered at a future time. Information about
future prices will enable the entrepreneur to estimate the future costs and returns of a
multistage project. Better estimates of future costs and returns enable investment to proceed
with more value-creating projects than would otherwise occur in an environment of high
uncertainty.
    As highlighted by Buckley and Casson (2002) and Rugman (1981), the following are among the
situations in which markets often fail and where it makes sense for companies to own their
activities.11
1.
Two companies’ cooperative production of a joint output involves numerous time lags and
intermediate deliveries. How are the companies going to set prices for each other for these
intermediate deliveries, going forward?How might the companies accommodate
adjustments to those prices in the event of unexpected contingencies? If a well-functioning
market exists to apprise the companies of prices set today for future deliveries of comparable
goods, a contract tied to knowledge of market prices could be executed. Without a well-
functioning market and the information it provides about prices, costly haggling over the
setting of future prices might jeopardize profitable opportunities for one or both companies.
The solution is often for the companies to merge and assign to one senior management team
responsibility for all decisions related to internal-transfer pricing.
Price negotiations for an ongoing set of transactions between a monopoly seller and a
monopoly buyer are likely to devolve into costly haggling. Each side can materially threaten
to prevent the other from being able to produce an intended output. An immediate solution
might be to execute a long-term contract that attempts to define all possible contingencies
and prescribe both parties’ responses to each contingency. In the event that contingencies
elude prediction or specification, companies are often well-advised to avoid contracting and
instead merge.
A prospective seller of proprietary knowledge is unable to reveal the true and complete
nature of that knowledge without, in effect, giving it away for free, and a prospective buyer,
knowing that the seller has more knowledge, faces considerable uncertainty in agreeing to
the price being asked. To avoid costly haggling, the seller can eliminate the risk by acquiring
the buyer’s business or establishing a new internal operation to compete with the buyer.
The value of a knowledge product is known, but there is an aspect of such products that can
occasion market failure. We presume that considerable investment was required to produce
this knowledge, but its ongoing use incurs zero (or almost zero) marginal cost of production.
A competitive market would set the price of the knowledge close to zero, the marginal cost,


706-448
Module Note—Introduction to Global Strategy
but the monopoly owner would then have little or no incentive to sell the knowledge. Even
if the owner wanted to sell, prospective buyers would worry that the owner might have an
incentive to flood the market with other sales at even lower prices in the future. Because
knowledge once produced can often be transferred at low or zero marginal cost, it takes on
the character of a public good. Markets are notoriously inefficient at pricing and providing
adequate incentives through prices for sellers to want to sell—and buyers to want to buy—
public goods. Because of this, it often makes sense for sellers and buyers of public goods to
merge and decide jointly how best to maximize the profitability of the knowledge.
    Besides market failure, companies might have three other motivations to own their foreign
activities.
1.
For a company that has developed and exploited a competitive advantage to build market
power in its home market, what might be the incentive for it to extend its competitive
advantage and market dominance to other geographic markets? Extending delivery of its
products and services to as many geographic markets as can be profitably served might
enable the company to (a) optimize returns on its prior investment in competitive advantage,
and (b) preempt the creation or consolidation of foreign competitors. With respect to (b), the
company might worry that foreign partners to which it licenses its technology (or other
aspects of its competitive advantage) will gain the expertise to one day challenge it in its own
market. Fear of creating future foreign competitors might lead the company to attempt to
either buy out local incumbents in the foreign host markets or establish a large enough
foreign presence to discourage potential competitors through vigorous competition. This
“market power” explanation of foreign ownership has explained the nature of foreign direct
investment in a number of industries and time periods.12
Duties and taxes imposed by local host governments on market transactions and local
income are often sufficient incentive for multinational companies to internalize greater
numbers and more types of transactions, which in turn provides a legal incentive for the
company to set prices for intermediate goods and decide where within its network of
affiliates to declare profits.13
In the event that the market works for pricing the sale of a given technology, but transfer of
the technology involves internal tacit knowledge that is difficult to explain or teach, a
multinational might find that even within the context of a well-functioning market, it can
realize greater profit from owning the foreign transfer and application of its technology. In
other words, the company itself might be the low-cost replicator of knowledge that is
intrinsically difficult to transfer to foreign operations.14
2.
3.
  As highlighted by Buckley and Casson (2002), we can thus identify specific circumstances under
which one is likely to see ownership of activities that extend across borders.15
1.
Research and development projects are often lengthy, requiring both long-term evaluation of
returns and short-term coordination of multiple sources of project input. In the absence of
well-functioning markets that can deliver price information, a company can often benefit
from internalizing a long-term research and development project or its implementation
across borders.
Team processes are often applied to some of the knowledge-generating tasks needed to
create value within a company. With teams, though, it can be difficult to verify and assign a
value to individual contributions through a formal market contract. Consider a retail
clothing store that needs information from its store managers about what individual
customers think the store is not providing but that they want to buy. The company might
2.
6


Module Note—Introduction to Global Strategy
706-448
3.
4.
find it difficult to write a market contract stipulating that the store will compensate the
manager who provides a certain type or quantity of customer information with a certain
amount of money. Because stores might have difficulty knowing ex ante how the market
will value managers’ information, and managers, knowing that stores will find it difficult to
compensate them directly and accurately for their information, will have little incentive to
devote time to gathering information, it often makes sense for stores to make store managers
into company employees and internalize the task of collecting customer feedback within
stores. A range of human resource practices can be used in conjunction with long-term
evaluation to build trust and reputation with employees. Because it can be difficult to assign
a value to a single contribution made on a given day, companies can use repeated evaluation
and supervision to fairly judge and compensate employees over time. Such up-and-close
interaction, together with accumulated company-level trust and reputation, can motivate
employees in a well-managed company, whose individual contributions might be difficult to
verify and directly compensate in every instance, to nevertheless make significant
investments of time that contribute to the company’s success.
Buyer uncertainty with respect to the true value of a knowledge-based product is likely to
deter successful market exchange, when the knowledge is difficult to patent or otherwise
protect legally. Consequently, it often makes sense for the seller of an unpatentable
knowledge product, the nature of which cannot be divulged without effectively giving it
away for free, to forward-integrate into the buyer’s business.
Knowledge is a public good, and because of the zero or non-zero marginal cost of producing
a public good, sellers will see market prices set too low and buyers worrying that the sellers
might try to maximize profits by later selling the knowledge at ever lower prices to others
who might compete with the original buyers. Companies sometimes address this
circumstance by carving up defined geographic boundaries within which their licensees can
do business, but it can prove costly to police licensees across geographic boundaries. It is
often more cost-effective for the original producer of the knowledge to internalize and own
the knowledge-based activity even as it is transplanted to other countries.
    In summary, multinational companies, like other purely local companies, bring market activities
within the organization whenever the marginal benefits and costs of the activities are not being
accurately reflected in market prices.16 As one learns from the study of competitive advantage, a
company might discover a unique combination of activities and go on to master coordination of the
constituent elements. If the knowledge needed to coordinate the activities becomes too complex to be
taught and implemented cost effectively outside the company, it clearly makes sense for the company
to own and direct its global expansion.
Organizational Modes of Market Entry
    A company that decides that its new global activities should be performed within the organization
must also decide whether to extend some degree of minority ownership to local partners more
knowledgeable of foreign institutions. Specifically, should the company expand through 100%
ownership and control, or through shared control with an outside partner? Multinationals, because
they fear financial expropriation and loss of intellectual property, tend to prefer complete control
over their subsidiaries. Although some of this fear is rational, some of it masks underlying
managerial biases toward control and empire-building. Companies that take on an outside partner
often do so to acquire (1) market knowledge that foreign investors cannot easily purchase, (2) control
over a key segment of the local value chain that would otherwise block entry, or (3) access to political
connections and the inexpensive resources (such as finance and technology) that can be acquired
7


706-448
Module Note—Introduction to Global Strategy
from them. Local governments sometimes use policy to compel foreign investors to engage local
partners; in 2005, for example, the Chinese government still required foreign investors in many
industries to seek out Chinese partners.17
   A foreign investor that chooses to invest with the help of a local partner must determine the
structure of the relationship. One dimension of partnership structure relates to control. A joint
venture is a shared, legally defined entity owned in specified percentages by the foreign investor and
outside partner. Strategic alliances and other types of partnerships that do not necessarily exist in
legal form leave issues of control more open to negotiation and change. Until the 1990s, foreign
investors tended to pursue joint ventures and surrender some control over joint assets. But because
they value control over their assets, companies tend to give up control rights only when they are paid
or compelled to do so. Recent research confirms that host-country governments’ elimination of
restrictions on investment has served as a disincentive for U.S. companies to participate in joint
ventures.18
   Foreign investors that decide to enter emerging economies must consider additional issues.
Expropriation is a serious concern in any country in which legal institutions are weak and political
discretion is high. A politically connected local company can just as easily use its connections to
directly expropriate its foreign partner. Expropriation is thus a concern with respect to not only local
governments but politically connected local firms.19
    Foreign companies have used various strategies for reducing the risk of expropriation. Most
commonly, they have sought to maintain control over the most valuable resources, including the flow
of knowledge and finance to the local partner. Some have created strong incentives for local partners
to jointly maximize profits and then have carefully monitored the local partners through joint control
of the shared assets. Other foreign companies have split activities across borders and rented foreign
legal jurisdictions to deal with contract disputes. Foreign investors that face discrimination in their
host countries sometimes form consortia or seek home-government support to lobby for property-
rights protection. Foreign companies have also taken on locally respected and influential passive
investors, trained their suppliers in global best practices, paid above-market wages and salaries, and
made contributions to local institutions such as universities and research institutes, to diminish the
liability of “foreignness”; by doing so they hope local customers, business partners, and host
governments will perceive them as at least nominally “local” companies.20
Reconfiguring the Global Organization
    A foreign company that has expanded to a new country must determine whether that expansion
requires a reorganization of its global operations to improve operational effectiveness and
productivity. Many companies change their organizational structure as they become more globally
diversified.21 As we learned earlier in strategy and organizational behavior courses, companies seek
to foster internal consistency between functional practices and organizational design. Consequently,
companies that adopt an aggregation-oriented strategy for global operations tend to be more
centralized to ensure that decision-making authority and accountability are located where the key
strategic decisions are being made. For products being standardized and sold in similar ways around
the world, layers of bureaucracy between the central site and global sales offices are unwanted.
Aggregators therefore tend to organize around either a central home office or a set of product
divisions that have global responsibility for production and sales.
   Companies that have chosen an adaptation strategy often put organizational power closer to the
individual country market. If they choose to customize products for local applications, they typically
8


Module Note—Introduction to Global Strategy
706-448
invest decision-making authority and accountability in the managers closest to the consumers. Such
companies tend to organize around strong, country-level subsidiaries and empower local managers
to make critical decisions about product development and marketing.
   Companies that seek to benefit from adaptation, aggregation, and arbitrage or who are driven by
competitors to do all three, will face the greatest organizational challenge. Companies that
successfully adapt, aggregate, and arbitrage are able to centralize certain key activities at
headquarters, leave others in the hands of local operations, and distribute still others to specialized
locations around the world. But the requisite combination of centralization, decentralization, and
regional agglomeration creates organizational frictions that few companies have been able to
overcome. There are, nevertheless, some examples of companies that have mastered numerous
aspects of this managerial challenge.22
Conclusion
    Companies that seek to become more global must carefully evaluate location-specific institutional
differences among countries. They must measure these differences precisely and determine whether
market failures provide opportunities to expand their business across borders. To do this effectively
they need to learn how foreign markets are structured. Often, as a 2001 study showed, an industry
that is highly concentrated and profitable in one country can have a far less attractive industry
structure and be unprofitable overseas.23 This circumstance results directly from institutions that
have acted over decades to affect company entry, means of finance, and production technology and
influence consumer tastes and preferences. Failure to study these differences carefully and devise
new ways to benefit from them can damage a company that currently enjoys a competitive advantage
in its home market. Careful study of these cross-country differences, on the other hand, often reveals
market failures that can be turned into global opportunities for adaptation, aggregation, or arbitrage,
or some combination thereof. Having selected a set of global activities, a company must align its
organizational practices and other functional activities with its new global strategy.
9


706-448
Module Note—Introduction to Global Strategy
Endnotes
     The results reported in this paragraph are from Jeffrey Frankel and Andrew Rose, “An Estimate of the
Effect of Common Currencies on Trade and Income,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (May 2002): 437-466. For
a description of different types of cultural and institutional distance and how they affect globalization, see
Pankaj Ghemawat, “Distance Still Matters: The Hard Reality of Global Expansion,” Harvard Business Review 79
(September 2001): 137–147.
    See Jordan I. Siegel, Amir Licht, and Shalom Schwartz, “Egalitarianism and International Investment,”
unpublished working paper (Boston: Harvard Business School, 2006).
    See Jordan I. Siegel, Amir Licht, and Shalom Schwartz, “Egalitarianism and International Investment,”
unpublished working paper (Boston: Harvard Business School, 2006).
     Although companies can still benefit enormously from cross-listing, the process is primarily one of
reputational bonding. Companies signal their quality by listing on a major U.S. exchange, then prove their
quality by respecting outside shareholders’ rights and assets during both good and (especially) bad economic
times in the company’s principal market of operation. For more information on reputational bonding, see Jordan
Siegel, “Can Foreign Firms Bond Themselves Effectively by Renting U.S. Securities Laws?” Journal of Financial
Economics 75 (February 2005): 319–359.
     For an illustration of how institutional differences prevent global convergence in production methods, see
Mauro Guillén, The Limits of Convergence: Globalization and Organizational Change in Argentina, South Korea, and
Spain (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000). For an example of how institutional regimes foster different
norms of business organization, see Tarun Khanna and Krishna Palepu, “Is Group Affiliation Profitable in
Emerging Markets? An Analysis of Diversified Indian Business Groups,” The Journal of Finance 55 (April 2000):
867–891.
     A world characterized by neither complete market integration nor isolation has been termed
“semiglobalization” by Pankaj Ghemawat, who explains this concept and what it means for strategy in
“Semiglobalization and International Business Strategy,” Journal of International Business Studies 34 (March 2003):
138–152.
      For more on the concepts of adaptation, aggregation, and arbitrage, see Pankaj Ghemawat, “The Forgotten
Strategy,” Harvard Business Review 81 (November 2003): 76–84.
      Ann E. Harrison and Margaret S. McMillan, “Does Direct Foreign Investment Affect Domestic Credit
Constraints?” Journal of International Economics 61 (October 2003): 73-100. See also Mihir A. Desai, C. Fritz Foley,
and James R. Hines Jr., “A Multinational Perspective on Capital Structure Choice and Internal Capital Markets,”
The Journal of Finance 59 (December 2004): 2451–2488.
     For a more complete description of these intermediate strategies, see Pankaj Ghemawat, “Semiglobalization
and International Business Strategy,” Journal of International Business Studies 34 (March 2003): 138–152. For
empirical evidence on the importance of regional strategies for multinational firms, see Alan M. Rugman, The
Regional Multinationals; MNEs and ‘Global’ Strategic Management (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2005).
     This section draws on Jean-Francois Hennart, The Theory of the Multinational Enterprise (Ann Arbor:
University of Michigan, 1982).
       The following section draws on Peter J. Buckley and Mark C. Casson, The Future of the Multinational
              thEnterprise (25 Anniversary Edition) (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2002). It also draws on Alan M. Rugman,
Inside the Multinationals; The Economics of Internal Markets (London: Croom Helm, 1981). For useful textbook
treatments of these subjects, see Alan M. Rugman, Donald J. Lecraw, and Laurence D. Booth, International
Business: Firm and Environment, 2nd ed. (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1985); and Alan M. Rugman and Richard M.rdHodgetts, International Business; A Strategic Management Approach, 3 ed. (Harlow, England: Pearson Education,
2002).



Module Note—Introduction to Global Strategy
706-448
       See Stephen Hymer, The International Operations of National Firms (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1976); Frederick
T. Knickerbocker, Oligopolistic Reaction and the Multinational Enterprise (Cambridge: Harvard University Press,
1973); and Pankaj Ghemawat and Catherine Thomas, “Multinational Enterprises in the Cement Industry: Firm
Interaction and Foreign Direct Investment,” unpublished working paper (Boston: Harvard Business School,
2005).
      See Peter J. Buckley and Mark C. Casson, The Future of the Multinational Enterprise (25 Anniversary
Edition) (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2002).
      For the first mention of this concept, see Frederick T. Knickerbocker, Oligopolistic Reaction and the
Multinational Enterprise (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1973). This argument has been more extensively
advocated by Bruce Kogut and Udo Zander, "Knowledge of the Firm and the Evolutionary Theory of the
Multinational Corporation," Journal of International Business Studies 24 (1993): 625–645.
      The following section draws on Peter J. Buckley and Mark C. Casson, The Future of the Multinational
              thEnterprise (25 Anniversary Edition) (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2002).
     For more information, see Richard E. Caves, Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1982/1996) and Jean-François Hennart, A Theory of Multinational Enterprise (Ann
Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1982).
      The classic texts on foreign direct investment are Stephen Herbert Hymer, The International Operations of
National Firms: A Study of Direct Foreign Investment (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1976) and Yair Aharoni, The Foreign
Investment Decision Process (Boston: Harvard University Press, 1966).
      See Mihir Desai, C. Fritz Foley, and James R. Hines Jr., “The Costs of Shared Ownership: Evidence from
International Joint Ventures,” Journal of Financial Economics 73 (2004): 323–374.
      For more information on the risks of local partnering, see Witold J. Henisz, “The Institutional Environment
for Multinational Investment,” Journal of Law, Economics & Organization 16 (October 2000): 334–364; and Witold J.
Henisz and Oliver E. Williamson, “Comparative Economic Organization—Within and Between Countries,”
Business and Politics 1 (November 1999): 261–276.
      See Theodore H. Moran, Multinational Corporations and the Politics of Dependence: Copper in Chile (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1974); Jonathan Eaton and Mark Gersovitz, “Country Risk: Economic Prospects,” in
Managing International Risk, ed. Richard J. Herring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983); Raymond
Vernon, “Organizational and Institutional Responses to International Risk,” in Managing International Risk, ed.
Richard J. Herring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983); and Witold J. Henisz and Bennet A. Zelner,
“Political Risk Management: A Strategic Perspective,” in International Political Risk Management, ed. Theodore H.
Moran (Washington, DC: World Bank, 2004).
      See John M. Stopford and Louis T. Wells, Jr., Managing the Multinational Enterprise; Organization of the
Firm and Ownership of the Subsidiaries (New York: Basic Books, 1972).
       For more information on so-called “transnational firms,” those that learned how to centralize, decentralize,
and network different activities at the same time, see Christopher A. Bartlett and Sumantra Ghoshal, Managing
Across Borders: The Transnational Solution, 2nd ed. (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1998). For further case
illustrations of transnational management, see Christopher A. Bartlett, Sumantra Ghoshal, and Julian
Birkinshaw, Transnational Management: Text, Cases, and Readings in Cross Border Management, 4th ed. (Boston:
McGraw-Hill, 2004).
     See Tarun Khanna and Jan Rivkin, “The Structure of Profitability Around the World,” unpublished
working paper no. 01-056 (Boston: Harvard Business School, 2001).



No comments:

Post a Comment